Democracia y Política

Is Democracy Dead?

Tony Blair: For True Democracy, the Right to Vote Is Not Enough

Turning Point: Russia annexes Crimea, formerly an autonomous area of Ukraine.

Democracy is not in good shape. Many systems seem dysfunctional: The U.S. Congress, the coalition government in the U.K., and many governments in Europe have had difficulty making the decisions necessary to finding a way back to economic growth. Some fledgling democracies seem, in the short term at least, less competent to serve the needs of their citizens than some autocracies are.

Take all this together and add the profound nature of the challenges of recent times — the extremism convulsing whole nations in the Middle East and beyond; the ongoing financial crisis in Europe; the conflict in eastern Ukraine and Russia’s annexation of Crimea — and it is not surprising that we have seen the rise of far-right parties in Europe and a general sense of malaise and disillusionment with democratic politics. Suddenly to some, Putinism — the cult of the strong leader who goes in the direction he pleases, seemingly contemptuous of opposition — has its appeal.

We have become complacent about democracy. It remains the system of choice. It remains what free people freely choose. But it has what I would call an “efficacy” challenge: Its values are right, but it is too often failing to deliver. In a world of change, where countries, communities and corporations must constantly adapt to keep up, democracy seems slow, bureaucratic and weak. In this sense it is failing its citizens. Why has this happened and what should we do about it?

We have forgotten that theories are only as good as they work in practice. So the technical nuts and bolts of democratic systems matter. The basic principle that the people should elect their government remains popular and obviously right, but its implementation seems to have gone awry. It is time to debate how to improve democracy, how to modernize it. Traditionally this debate has been dominated by issues of transparency and honesty, as with, for example, the discussion in the U.K. about expense reimbursements for members of parliament.

But the disillusionment with democratic governments is really about people believing that the changes they need in their lives can’t happen quickly enough. It is a practical challenge. People regularly frame it differently: They say that the government isn’t listening. But often the government is listening — it is rather that the voices that reach officials are saying different things. It is effective decision-making through strong leadership that is the missing element. Why is this?

In recent years, certain changes that have taken place in Western democracies have decreased the system’s efficacy.

In both the U.S. and the U.K., increasingly, as a result of the way constituencies’ boundaries have been drawn, some have fallen into the “ownership” of parties. So if you win your party’s nomination to be the candidate, you win the seat. This pushes would-be candidates to take positions that appeal to the party activists who select nominees, not to the broader public. So politicians have been moving away from the center ground — where the public tends to congregate — to the detriment of policy-making.

In such a system, the emphasis is on striking political positions, not on delivering evidence-based solutions. In fact, modern governance is mainly a nonideological business.

In addition, the media in many Western countries have become more partisan as conventional audiences shrivel and news organizations see the best commercial opportunity in roiling their most loyal viewers and connecting with their specific interests.

Then there have grown up powerful interest groups that can stand in the way of substantial and necessary reform. Anyone who has ever tried to reform an education system, for example, knows how tough and bitter a struggle it is. The bureaucracy fights change. The teachers’ unions fight change. The public gets whipped up to defeat change even when it is in the public’s own interest. The nearest I came to losing my job as prime minister was not over policies of war and peace, but over education reforms. The effort to reform health care has similar characteristics.

Yet since the world is changing so fast, updating government systems is essential.

The impact of the lack of reform is felt by the public. People need better services, have higher expectations, but as any politician can tell you, they don’t want to pay more for them. So the absence of reform, particularly in an era of tight budgets, is immensely challenging. Thus you have the curious paradox of modern leadership: There has to be reform to satisfy rising public demands, but the public can be easily mobilized to oppose those reforms. Therefore politicians often back off the change, which then increases voters’ disillusionment with the political process.

Look at European nations like France, Italy, Spain and Greece, which are struggling to reform their tax systems, to change how public benefits are distributed, or to decrease systemic redundancies. The public blowback against reform is intense and yet there really is no alternative. Meanwhile the European Union is unable to take measures to stimulate growth, the essential accompaniment to reform.

Examine the changes in the private sector over the past 20 years. Look at the top companies by market capitalization and how new names have displaced the old. This is the way of the world, except in government. We go along in the same old way — unable to change, due in part to top-down bureaucracies that manage the status quo instead of changing it.

Technology alone could transform the way education and health care work. It could revolutionize learning and teaching. It could create whole new pathways of diagnosis and treatment. In the best places this is happening, but not in most. It is this — the efficacy gap — that is the real cause of political disillusionment and why people go running after populist solutions that aren’t really solutions at all. This is what we need to fix.

Moreover, at the very time when leadership is needed, the gene pool of political leaders has shrunk. How many leaders and, for that matter, followers in a parliament or congress have real-life experience in responsible positions outside of politics? Today it is very common for a young person interested in politics to graduate from university, go to work for a politician as a researcher or political analyst, and then transition straight into an elected position.

I only spent seven years working in the private sector before entering politics, but it was a crucial, formative time. I learned about business and about people in a way that was greatly beneficial when I later came to govern. In particular, I learned the difference between academic political ideas and policies suited to “real world” application.

On top of this — and only an ex-politician can say this — politicians are not really well paid by the standards of those who are successful in the private sector. This restricts the attractions of a political career, at exactly the time when we most need the gene pool of our politicians to be varied, vibrant and vigorous.

The result of all this, for those who then rise to the top position in a democracy, is that it can be hard to get things done — hence the “efficacy challenge.” This challenge is magnified by social media, which is itself a revolutionary phenomenon. Waves of emotion on issues used to build to tidal strength relatively slowly; they now reach tsunami force within days, even hours. Politicians’ desire for impact too often obscures the value of balance.

Political leaders find this quite disorienting. A leader has to calibrate leadership and public opinion, be out in front of it, but not too much so. He or she has to judge sentiment finely, but making this judgment is hard if you’re governing by Twitter feed. Social media is exciting and can effect real and positive change, but it is also the domain of the loudmouth — and those who shout loudest don’t necessarily deserve to be heard most.

The answer to this democratic malaise may be partly a change in the relationship between governing and governed. People have to accept that governing involves difficult choices, and politicians ought to be respected for making them, not abused. It may involve changing the rules — for example, allowing greater interchange between the public and private sectors. It may be that parliaments need to function differently. In some countries, there may even be need for constitutional changes.

The time has come to put this issue squarely on the table. The simple right to vote is not enough: Systems need to deliver results for the people. They do not at present. We should not leave voters with a choice between dictatorship and populism. If we truly believe in democracy, the time has come to improve it.

Tony Blair was prime minister of Britain from 1997 to 2007.

 

 

2 comentarios

  1. Supongo que puede comentarse en español un artículo en inglés. Creo que el Sr. Blair hace la pregunta incorrecta, pues no es la democracia lo que funciona mal, sino la nación-estado. Una dictadura no garantiza que los países crezcan económicamente, cuando las primeras fisuras en el espectacular crecimiento chino comienzan a asomarse. La democracia funciona mejor porque los sistemas complejos tienen propiedades emergentes que no están presentes en los componentes individuales.
    Para la economía clásica la mano misteriosa del mercado estaba basada en la eficiencia del decisor individual. Se lo postulaba como miembro de la especie homo œconomicus, hombre económicamente racional. Los mo­delos del comportamiento microeconómico postulaban competencia per­fecta e información transparente. El mercado era perfecto porque el átomo que lo componía, el decisor individual, era perfecto. La propiedad del conjunto estaba presente en el componente.
    En cambio, la más moderna y poderosa corriente del pensamiento científico en general, y del pensamiento social en particular, ha debido admitir esta realidad de los sistemas complejos: que éstos—el clima, la ecología, el sistema nervioso, la corteza terrestre, la sociedad—exhiben en su con­junto “propiedades emergentes” a pesar de que estas mismas propieda­des no se hallen en sus componentes individuales. En ilustración de Ilya Prigogine, Premio Nóbel de Química: si ante un ejército de hormigas que se desplaza por una pared, uno fija la atención en cualquier hormiga ele­gida al azar, podrá notar que la hormiga en cuestión despliega un com­portamiento verdaderamente errático. El pequeño insecto se dirigirá hacia adelante, luego se detendrá, dará una vuelta,
    se comunicará con una vecina, tornará a darse vuelta, etcétera. Pero el
    conjunto de las hor­migas tendrá una dirección claramente definida. Como lo ponen técni­camente Gregoire Nicolis y el mismo Ilya Prigogine en “Exploring Com­plexity” (Freeman, 1989): “Lo que es más sorprendente en muchas socie­dades de insectos es la existencia de dos escalas: una a nivel del indivi­duo y otra a nivel de la sociedad como conjunto donde, a pesar de la inefi­ciencia e impredecibilidad de los individuos, se
    desarrollan patrones cohe­rentes característicos de la especie a la escala de toda la colonia”. Hoy en día no es necesario suponer la racionalidad
    individual para postular la racionalidad del conjunto: el mercado es un
    mecanismo eficiente independientemente y por encima de la lógica de las
    decisiones individuales.
    Es esta característica natural de los sistemas complejos el más poderoso fundamento de la democracia y el mercado. A pesar de la imperfección política de los ciudadanos concretos, la democracia sabe encontrar el bien común mejor que otras formas de gobierno; a pesar de la imperfección económica de los consumidores el mercado es preferible como dis­tribuidor social. Por supuesto, los sistemas complejos, como el cuerpo humano, por ejemplo, pueden enfermarse, y se hace necesaria una acción correctiva. Los mercados y las democracias pueden comportarse muy mal en ocasiones, pero no es la solución eliminar esas instituciones, sino su tratamiento terapéutico.
    Por otra parte, las naciones-estado muestran un desempeño peor que el de las ciudades en el manejo de asuntos tales como una conducta ecológica sensata, y además de este asunto—el calentamiento global no se detiene en la frontera entre Brasil y Venezuela—, otros procesos transnacionales—terrorismo, narcotráfico, etc.—exigen la construcción de una polis a escala planetaria, basada sobre la noción última de una ciudadanía planetaria. Una moneda planetaria, por caso, eliminaría de un todo cualquier problema de cambio entre divisas, por cuanto sólo habría una.
    En cuanto a la democracia misma, la cosa no se detiene en la superposición de una democracia participativa (referendos) sobre una
    meramente representativa (Alvin Toffler, Megatrends, 1982); ahora emerge la posibilidad de una democracia deliberativa (James Fishkin, Democracy and deliberation, 1991), con desarrollo de software que la facilita.
    Por encima de todo, es preciso renovar la fe en el demos. Barbara Tuchman conjeturó en 1964 (The March of Folly): “The problem may
    not be so much a matter of educating officials for government as educating the electorate to recognize and reward integrity of character and to reject the ersatz.”

  2. Supongo que puede comentarse en español un artículo en inglés. Creo que el Sr. Blair hace la pregunta incorrecta, pues no es la democracia lo que funciona mal, sino la nación-estado. Una dictadura no garantiza que los países crezcan económicamente, cuando las primeras fisuras en el espectacular crecimiento chino comienzan a asomarse. La democracia funciona mejor porque los sistemas complejos tienen propiedades emergentes que no están presentes en los componentes individuales.
    Para la economía clásica la mano misteriosa del mercado estaba basada en la eficiencia del decisor individual. Se lo postulaba como miembro de la especie homo œconomicus, hombre económicamente racional. Los mo­delos del comportamiento microeconómico postulaban competencia per­fecta e información transparente. El mercado era perfecto porque el átomo que lo componía, el decisor individual, era perfecto. La propiedad del conjunto estaba presente en el componente.
    En cambio, la más moderna y poderosa corriente del pensamiento científico en general, y del pensamiento social en particular, ha debido admitir esta realidad de los sistemas complejos: que éstos—el clima, la ecología, el sistema nervioso, la corteza terrestre, la sociedad—exhiben en su con­junto “propiedades emergentes” a pesar de que estas mismas propieda­des no se hallen en sus componentes individuales. En ilustración de Ilya Prigogine, Premio Nóbel de Química: si ante un ejército de hormigas que se desplaza por una pared, uno fija la atención en cualquier hormiga ele­gida al azar, podrá notar que la hormiga en cuestión despliega un com­portamiento verdaderamente errático. El pequeño insecto se dirigirá hacia adelante, luego se detendrá, dará una vuelta,
    se comunicará con una vecina, tornará a darse vuelta, etcétera. Pero el conjunto de las hor­migas tendrá una dirección claramente definida. Como lo ponen técni­camente Gregoire Nicolis y el mismo Ilya Prigogine en “Exploring Com­plexity” (Freeman, 1989): “Lo que es más sorprendente en muchas socie­dades de insectos es la existencia de dos escalas: una a nivel del indivi­duo y otra a nivel de la sociedad como conjunto donde, a pesar de la inefi­ciencia e impredecibilidad de los individuos, se desarrollan patrones cohe­rentes característicos de la especie a la escala de toda la colonia”. Hoy en día no es necesario suponer la racionalidad individual para postular la racionalidad del conjunto: el mercado es un mecanismo eficiente independientemente y por encima de la lógica de las decisiones individuales.
    Es esta característica natural de los sistemas complejos el más poderoso fundamento de la democracia y el mercado. A pesar de la imperfección política de los ciudadanos concretos, la democracia sabe encontrar el bien común mejor que otras formas de gobierno; a pesar de la imperfección económica de los consumidores el mercado es preferible como dis­tribuidor social. Por supuesto, los sistemas complejos, como el cuerpo humano, por ejemplo, pueden enfermarse, y se hace necesaria una acción correctiva. Los mercados y las democracias pueden comportarse muy mal en ocasiones, pero no es la solución eliminar esas instituciones, sino su tratamiento terapéutico.
    Por otra parte, las naciones-estado muestran un desempeño peor que el de las ciudades en el manejo de asuntos tales como una conducta ecológica sensata, y además de este asunto—el calentamiento global no se detiene en la frontera entre Brasil y Venezuela—, otros procesos transnacionales—terrorismo, narcotráfico, etc.—exigen la construcción de una polis a escala planetaria, basada sobre la noción última de una ciudadanía planetaria. Una moneda planetaria, por caso, eliminaría de un todo cualquier problema de cambio entre divisas, por cuanto sólo habría una.
    En cuanto a la democracia misma, la cosa no se detiene en la superposición de una democracia participativa (referendos) sobre una meramente representativa (Alvin Toffler, Megatrends, 1982); ahora emerge la posibilidad de una democracia deliberativa (James Fishkin, Democracy and deliberation, 1991), con desarrollo de software que la facilita.
    Por encima de todo, es preciso renovar la fe en el demos. Barbara Tuchman conjeturó en 1964 (The March of Folly): “The problem may not be so much a matter of educating officials for government as educating the electorate to recognize and reward integrity of character and to reject the ersatz.”

Botón volver arriba